§ 瀏覽學位論文書目資料
  
系統識別號 U0002-2401201618020600
DOI 10.6846/TKU.2016.00766
論文名稱(中文) 考量多元動機與效用性質的決策模型及其相關實驗檢證
論文名稱(英文) Explorations of Utility in A Multi-Motivation Decision Model and the Related Experimental Tests
第三語言論文名稱
校院名稱 淡江大學
系所名稱(中文) 產業經濟學系博士班
系所名稱(英文) Department of Industrial Economics
外國學位學校名稱
外國學位學院名稱
外國學位研究所名稱
學年度 104
學期 1
出版年 105
研究生(中文) 于席正
研究生(英文) Hsi-Cheng Yu
學號 802540046
學位類別 博士
語言別 繁體中文
第二語言別
口試日期 2016-01-15
論文頁數 113頁
口試委員 指導教授 - 江莉莉
指導教授 - 林俊宏
委員 - 陳和全
委員 - 江莉莉
委員 - 林忠正
委員 - 池秉聰
委員 - 張文俊
關鍵字(中) 快樂
動機
社會順從
利他
心理取向
道德
外部性
皮古稅
Easterlin 悖論
關鍵字(英) happiness
motivation
social conformity
altruism
psychological orientation
morality
externality
Pigouvian tax
Easterlin paradox
第三語言關鍵字
學科別分類
中文摘要
本研究承續古典的效用主義思想,建立一個結合心理機制與外部行為的決策模型,期對人類行為有更豐富的解釋,並凸顯自利以外的人性價值。參考模型推論衍生的重要意涵,公共政策制定者得以更充分掌握個體的決策思維,以更細膩的方法解決公眾利益的衝突,或誘導社會大眾跳脫自利的框架,讓社會福祉的提升水到渠成。
    全文分三部分,首先是多元動機決策模型的建立。考量始自刺激出現,終於現實行為決策間的心理歷程,以及認知系統的理性決策能力,建構情緒與認知兩系統共同運作的模型,探討心理動機對決策與體驗效用的影響。藉由心理動機與實質決策間的動態調整過程,呈現個體完整的生命歷程。利用數值模擬生命歷程的快樂演進趨勢,呈現倒 U 的型態;如若強化利他動機,將提高歷程中的快樂軌跡。隨著個人的所得增加,基於心理特徵的機會成本增加、社會標準提高與本能性動機下的定位點與時俱進等三項因素,可能肇致 Easterlin paradox 的發生。
    第二部分旨在驗證本研究的決策模型之多元動機存在假設。擬定共有資源分配議題,利用自行開發的「情境延伸法」進行行為實驗。透過逐步凸顯多元動機之方法,蒐集動機存在性與受重視程度、對應的最適決策以及預擬快樂程度等數據進行統計分析。主要結果顯示,社會性動機將使個體減少自身利得的取用。然而,相對於單純凸顯自利動機的情境,凸顯社會性動機後的快樂感受顯著減少。惟利他動機的喚起不但進一步減少共有資源的取用,且能夠補償社會性動機的快樂損失,使個體的整體快樂感受無異於純自利動機下的情境。
    第三部分試圖將道德內化於個體的決策模型中,以刻劃利他動機的形成與社會定位點的由來。運用融合道德的決策模型,探討負外部性議題,並驗證道德與傳統皮古稅在修正外部性的對應性。結果顯示在外部性情況下,道德同樣能藉由個體對社會情感的重視來達成社會最適狀態。另一方面,基於道德內化而形成的利他動機,更能有效約束負外部性的行動,尤其重要者,利他動機係屬心理酬賞而非懲罰。
英文摘要
Based on the utilitarianism, this study develops a decision model, integrating a mental mechanism with decision-makings, to provide profound explanations for human behavior and to shed light on the value of human nature besides self-interest. This decision model could be employed to help understand people’s decision process. The policy implications lead a government to design a meticulous way to deal with the conflicts of private interests or to induce people to dismiss the self-interest frame so as to yield the improvement of social welfare.
    The thesis contains three parts. In the first part we set up a multi-motivation decision model in which the mental process of stimulus receiving, perception, and decision is embedded. A person’s behavior is determined by an interaction between an affective system and a cognitive system. Using this model, we could investigate the impacts of motivations on a person’s decision. Applying this model to intertemporal choice, we can trace a person’s lifetime decisions and happiness. A numerical simulation shows that lifetime happiness has an inverted-U pattern. Moreover, in cases where altruistic motivation is evoked, a person can attain a high path of happiness evolution. In addition, through the process of income growth, the negative anchoring effect caused by the lifting of social standards, treadmill effects, and the rise in shadow prices of psychological characteristics, might give rise to the Easterlin paradox.
    The second part is aimed to test the assumptions of multiple motivations. We design a series of behavioral experiments, called extensional contextual experiments, to examine the determinants of money payoff by eliciting various motives one-by-one. We find that the motivations of self-interest, social conformity and we-world are actually the main driving forces in deciding the allocation between money payoff and donation. The motivation of social conformity pushes a person to reduce the desired payoff, which significantly decreases his/her anticipated degree of happiness. Once a person’s altruism is evoked, the desired payoff decreases further. Meanwhile happiness rises to the same level as anticipated with sole motive of self-interest.
    In the third part we intend to endogenize the formation of social anchor and the generation of altruistic motivation by incorporating morality in the multi-motivation decision framework. This model characterized by morality creation and function is used to analyze the potential correction effects of morality on externality. We show that equivalence exists between morality and the Pigouvian tax. We also point out a value of morality- that is, people with an altruistic motivation, experience enjoyment rather than pain, from self-fulfillment of morality.
第三語言摘要
論文目次
目錄
第一章  緒論	1
1.1研究動機與目的	1
1.2文獻回顧	5
1.2.1效用定義與性質	5
1.2.2動力心理學	8
1.2.3存在主義與人本心理學	11
1.2.4社會偏好	14
1.3論文架構	18
第二章  引入精神力場的決策模型	21
2.1本章前言	21
2.2精神力場假說	22
2.2.1重要的基因演化機制	23
2.2.2快樂的形成及其歷程	24
2.2.3要素投入達成快樂的媒介	29
2.2.4決策主體	33
2.3決策模型架構	35
2.3.1情緒系統的決策	35
2.3.2認知系統的決策	37
2.3.3參考點的逐期調整	40
2.4精神力場的啟示	42
2.4.1生命歷程的快樂變遷:基準模型 (benchmark) 的數值模擬	42
2.4.2意志與大我世界觀	47
2.4.3 Easterlin paradox 的解釋	50
2.5本章結語	52
第三章  快樂動機的行為實驗論證	55
3.1本章前言	55
3.2快樂計數法概述	56
3.3研究方法	57
3.3.1實驗參與者	57
3.3.2實驗目標	58
3.3.3實驗工作與流程	59
3.4實驗方法	60
3.4.1單位快樂計數法施行方式	60
3.4.2純自利狀態下快樂基本計數	60
3.4.3動機—決策—預擬快樂之測度:情境延伸法運用	61
3.5資料處理與分析	64
3.6實驗結果	68
3.6.1純自利狀態下快樂的形態與特性	68
3.6.2快樂動機的存在性	69
3.6.3動機與最適現金利得	70
3.6.4動機與預擬快樂感受	75
3.7實驗討論	77
3.8本章結語	81
第四章  外部性議題的新解	83
4.1 本章前言	83
4.2多元動機下的道德角色	84
4.3外部性議題的理論架構	86
4.3.1傳統外部性模型	87
4.3.2引入道德的外部性模型	87
4.4皮古稅課徵與道德內生化的關聯性	91
4.4.1皮古稅	91
4.4.2道德的影響	92
4.4.3皮古稅課徵與道德內生化的關聯性	93
4.5本章結語	94
第五章  本文結論	95
參考文獻	100
附錄	110
一、模擬函數與數值設定	110
二、表圖附錄	112

表圖目錄
表 3.1 純自利狀態下快樂程度的敘述統計量	69
表 3.2 快樂動機存在性的統計推論	71
表 3.3 各題組 (情境) 新增動機之重視程度的統計推論	71
表 3.4 題組 5 (情境 5) 中各動機之重視程度的統計推論	72
表 3.5 題組 (情境) 間最適現金利得平均數差的成對比較	73
表 3.6 題組 (情境) 間總和快樂程度平均數差的成對比較	77
表 3.7 動機、行為決策與總和快樂程度	79
附表 1各期參考點、心理狀態與快樂感受的模擬結果	112

圖 2.1 決策流程	22
圖 2.2 精神力場示意圖	31
圖 2.3 精神力場 (基準模型)	43
圖 2.4 各期實際快樂感受 (基準模型a 與形成我世界動機b 之比較)	47
圖 2.5 各期實際幸福感受 (基準模型a 與所得和社會標準同步增加d 之比較)	52
圖 3.1 題組 2 填答流程圖	66
圖 3.2 題組 3~5 填答流程圖	67
圖 3.3 快樂動機受重視程度的動態變化	72
附圖 1各期實際快樂感受 (基準模型a與所得恆常增加c之比較)	113
參考文獻
張春興,《現代心理學》,第1版。台北市:東華書局,2007。
張春興,《張氏心理學辭典》,重訂1版。台北市:東華書局,2008。
張景然、吳芝儀,《團體諮商的理論與實務》。台北:揚智,1995。
傅佩榮,《一本就通:西方心理學史》,第1版。台北市:聯經,2011。
黃有光,《福利經濟學》,第 1 版。台北市:茂昌,1999。
海德格的存在哲學。南華大學。http://www.nhu.edu.tw/~sts/class/class_03_2.htm.
Adelman, H. S., L. Taylor and P. Nelson, “Minors' dissatisfaction with their life circumstances,” Child Psychiatry and Human Development, 1989, 20 (2), 135-147.
Asch, S. E., “Opinions and social pressure”, Scientific American, 1955, 193 (5), 31–35.
Akerlof, G. A., “A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence,” the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1980, 94 (4), 749-775.
___________ “The economics of caste and of the rat race and other woeful tales,” the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1976, 90 (4), 599-617.
___________ “Labor contracts as partial gift exchange,” the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1982, 97 (4), 543-569.
___________ “Social distance and social decisions,” Econometrica, 1997, 65 (5), 1005-1028.
Arkoff, A., Psychology and Personal Growth, 1980, 2nd ed. Boston : Allyn and Bacon, 1980.
Barro, R. J., “Are government bonds net wealth? ,” Journal of Political Economy, 1974, (82)6, 1095-1117
Baumeister, R. F. and K. D. Vohs, “Willpower, choice, and self-control,” in George Loewenstein, D. Read and R. F. Baumeister eds., Time and decision: Economic and psychological perspectives on intertemporal choice, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2003, 201-216.
Becker, G. S., “Irrational behavior and economic theory”, Journal of Political Economy, 1962, 70 (1), 1-13.
___________ “A theory of social interactions,” Journal of Political Economy, 1974, 82 (6), 1063-1093.
___________ “Altruism, egoism, and genetic fitness: Economics and Sociobiology,” Journal of Economic Literature, 1976, 14 (3), 817-826.
___________ Accounting for Tastes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1996.
Bentham, J., An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation. Batoche Books, Kitchener, 1781 [2000].
Bernheim, B. D., “A theory of conformity,” Journal of Political Economy, 1994, 102 (5), 841-877.
Blanchflower, D. G. and A. J. Oswald, “Well-being over time in Britain and the USA”, Journal of Public Economics, 2004, 88, 1359-1386.
Boleyn-Fitzgerald, M., Picture of the Mind: What the New Neuroscience Tells Us about Who We Are. New Jersey: Pearson Education, Inc., 2010. 洪蘭(譯),《心智拼圖:從神經造影看大腦的成長、學習與改變》,台北市:遠流,2010。
Boring, E. G., A History of Experimental Psychology, 2nd ed. New York: Appleton-Century-Cfofts, 1950. 高覺敷 (譯),《實驗心理學史》,北京:商務印書館,2009。
Bradburn, N. M., The Structure of Psychological Well-being. Chicago: Aldine, 1969.
Corcoran, K., J. Crusius and T. Mussweiler, “Social comparison: motives, standards, and mechanisms,” Theories in social psychology, 2011, 119-139.
Csikszentmihalyi, M. and R. Larson, “Intrinsic rewards in school crime,” Crime and Delinquency, 1978, 24 (3), 322-335.
Deb, R., R. S. Gazzale and M. J. Kotchen, “Testing motives for charitable giving: A revealed-preference methodology with experimental evidence,” Journal of Public Economics, 2014, 120, 181-192.
Deutsch, M. and H. B. Gerard, “A study of normative and informational social influences upon individual judgment”, Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 1955, 51, 629-636.
Diener, E., “Subjective well-being: The science of happiness and a proposal for a national index,” American Psychologist, 2000, 55 (1), 34-43.
Diener, E., R. A. Emmons, R. J. Larsen and S. GRIFFIN, “The satisfaction with life scale,” Journal of Personality Assessment, 1985, 49 (1), 71-75.
Dufwenberg, M. and M. Lundholm, “Social norms and moral hazard,” The Economic Journal, 2001, 111 (473), 506-525.
Easterlin, R. A., “Does economic growth improve the human lot? some empirical evidence”, Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz (ed. by P. A. David and M. W. Reder). New York: Academic Press, Inc., 1974. 
Elster, J., “Social norms and economic theory,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1989, 3 (4), 99-117.
Fehr, E. and K. M. Schmidt, “A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation,” the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1999, 114 (3), 817-868.
Fehr, E. and S. Gächter, “Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments,” The American Economic Review, 2000, 90 (4), 980-994.
Festinger, L., “A theory of social comparison processes,” Human Relations, 1954, 7, 117-140.
Fischer, P. and S. Huddart, “Optimal contracting with endogenous social norms,” The American Economic Review, 2008, 98 (4), 1459-1475.
FitzGerald, M. J. T. and J. Folan-Curran, Clinical Neuroanatomy and Related Neuroscience. 4/e. Singapore: Elsevier, 2002.  簡基憲、黃步敏、李世雄、楊正峰、周明加、柯妙華(譯),《圖解臨床神經解剖學及神經科學》,台北縣:藝軒,2007。
Fong C. M., ”Evidence from an Experiment on Charity to Welfare Recipients: Reciprocity, Altruism and the Empathic Responsiveness Hypothesis,” The Economic Journal, 2007, 117 (522), 1008-1024.
Freud, S., Instincts and Their Vicissitudes. trans. by Joan Riviere, Collected Papers of S. Freud, London: Hogarth, 1915 [1949], 60-83.
Frey, B. S. and S. Meier, “Social comparisons and pro-social behavior: testing "conditional cooperation" in a field experiment,” The American Economic Review, 2004, 94 (5), 1717-1722.
Frith, U. and C. D. Frith, “Development and neurophysiology of mentalizing”, Philosophical Transactions B (Fruth, C.D. and D. Wolpert eds), Special issue on mechanisms of social interaction (2003).
Gusnard, D. A., E. Akbudak, G. L., Shulman and M. E. Raichle, “Medial prefrontal cortex and self-referential mental activity: relation to a default mode of brain function”, Proceedings of the National Academy Sciences of the United States of America, 2008, 98 (7), 4259–4264. 
Hausman, D.M. and M. S. McPherson, Economic Analysis, Moral Philosophy, and Public Policy. 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006.
Harbaugh, W. T., U. Mayr, and D. R. Burghart, “Neural responses to taxation and voluntary giving reveal motives for charitable donations”, Science. 2007, (316) 5831, 1622-1625.
Harris, L. T., S. M. McClure, W. van den Bos, J. D. Cohen, S. T. Fiske, “Regions of the MPFC Differentially Tuned to Social and Nonsocial Affective Evaluation,” Cognitive, Affective, & Behavior Neuroscience, 2007, 7 (4), 309-316.
Heidegger, M., Through Phenomenology to Thought. 3nd ed., W. J. RICHARDSON, Netherlands: M. Nijhoff, 1974.
Hicks J. R. and R. G. D. Allen, “A reconsideration of the theory of value. Part II. A Mathematical Theory of Individual Demand Functions,” Economica, 1934, 1 (2), 196-219. 
Iacoboni, M. and D. J. Siegel, “The implications of mirror neurons for psychotherapy,” day-long seminar, November 2004, San Francisco, Santa Rosa, CA: RJ Cassidy Seminar Recordings, Audio CD RCassidy.com.
Jevons, W. S., The theory of Political Economy. 1871 [2001], (New York: Palgrave).
___________ Essays on Economics. London: Macmillan, 1905.
Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky, “Prospect theory - Analysis of decision under risk,” Econometrica, 1979, 47 (2), 263-291.
Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky (Eds.), Choices, Values and Frames. New York: Cambridge University Press and the Russell Sage Foundation, 2000.
Kahneman, D., A. B. Krueger, D. A. Schkade, N. Schwarz and A. A. Stone, “A survey method for characterizing daily life experience: The day reconstruction method,” Science, 2004, 306 (5702), 1776-1780.
Kahneman, D., P. P. Wakker and R. Sarin, “Back to bentham? exploration of experienced utility”, the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1997, 112 (2), 375-405.
Kandel, E.R., J. H. Schwartz and T. M. Jessell, Principles of Neural Science. 4th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill, 2000.
Kaplow, L. and S. Shavell, “Moral rules, the moral sentiments, and behavior: Toward a theory of an optimal moral system,” Journal of Political Economy, ” 2007, 115 (3), 494-514.
Kluchare, V., M. A. Munneke, A. Smidts, G. Fernández, “Downregulation of the Posterior Medial Frontal Cortex Prevents Social Conformity,” Journal of Neuroscience, 2011, 17 (3), 11934-11940.
Kozma, A. and M. J. Stones, “The measurement of happiness: Development of the measurement of happiness: Development of the memorial university of newfoundland scale of happiness,” Journal of Gerontology, 1980, 35, 906-912.
Kőszegi B. and M. Rabin, “A model of reference-dependent preferences,” the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2006, 121 (4), 1133-1165. 
Lancaster, K.L., “A new approach to consumer theory,” Journal of Political Economy, 1966, 74, 132-57. 
LeDoux, J. E., The Emotional Brain: The Mysterious Underpinnings of Emotional Life. New York, NY: Simon and Schuster, 1996.
Lindbeck, A., “Incentives and social norms in household behavior,” The American Economic Review, 1997, 87 (2), 370-377.
Lindbeck, A., S. Nyberg and J. W. Weibull, “Social norms and economic incentives in the welfare state,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1999, 11 (1), 1-35.
Loewenstein, G. and T. O’Donoghue, “The heat of the moment: Modeling interactions between affect and deliberation,” 2007, Cornell Economics: http://www.economics.cornell.edu/edo1/heat.pdf (Retrieved March 10, 2013).
Luks, A., “Helper's high: Volunteering makes people feel good, physically and emotionally,” Psychology Today, 1988, 22 (10), 34-42.
Luttmer, E. F. P., “Neighbors as negatives: Relative earnings and well-being,” the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2005, 120 (3), 963-1002.
Lyubomirsky, S. and L. Ross, “Hedonic consequences of social comparison: A contrast of happy and unhappy people,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 1997, 73 (6), 1141-1157.
Marshall, A. H., Principles of Economics. 8th ed., London: Macmillan and Co., 1890 [1920].
Maslow, A. H., “A theory of human motivation,” Psychological Review, 1943, (50) 4, pp. 370-396.
___________ Motivation and Personality. New York: Harper and Row, 1954.  
___________ Motivation and Personality. 2nd ed., New York: Harper and Row, 1970
___________ The Farther Reaches of Human Nature. 1969. 林芳(譯),《人性能達的境界》,昆明:雲南人民出版社,1987。
___________ Toward a Psychology of Being. Star Publishing LLC, 1968 [2012].
McPherson, M.S., “Mill’s moral theory and the problem of preference change,” Ethics, 1982, 92(2), 252-273.
Menger, C., Principals of Economics. trans. by James Dingwall and Bert F. Hoselitz, (Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute), 1871 [2007].
Ng, Yew-Kwang, “Happiness surveys: Some comparability issues and an     exploratory survey based on just perceivable increments,” Social Indicators Research, 1996, 38, 1-27.
Ostrom, E., “A behavioral approach to the rational-choice theory of collective action,” American Political Science Review, 1998, 92 (1), 1-22.
Papez J. W., “A proposed mechanism of emotion,” Arch Neurol Psychiatry, 1937, 38 (4), 725-743.
Pareto, V., Manual of Political Economy. trans. by Ann Schwier, a translation of the 1927 french edition, New York: Augustus M. K., 1906 [1971].
Pérez-Asenjo, E., “If happiness is relative, against whom do we compare ourselves? Implications for labour supply,” Journal of Population Economics, 2011, 24 (4), 1411-1442.
Posner, R.A. and E.B. Rasmusen, “Creating and enforcing norms, with special reference to sanctions,” International Review of Law and Economics, 1999, 19, 369-382.
Post, S. G., “Altruism, happiness, and health: It’s good to be good,” International Journal of Behavioral Medicine, 2005, 12 (2), 66-77.
Raz, A. and J. Buhle, “Typologies of attention networks,” Nature Reviews Neuroscience, 2006, 7 (5), 367-379.
Roberts, R. D., “A positive model of private charity and public transfers,” Journal of Political Economy, 1984, 92 (1), 136-148.
Rogers, C., On Becoming a Person: A Therapist's View of Psychotherapy. London: Constable, 1961.
Schubert, C., “Pursuing happiness,” Kyklos, 2012, 65 (2), 245-261.
Schwartz, B., A. Ward, J. Monterosso, S. Lyubomirsky, K. White and D. R. Lehman, “Maximizing versus satisficing: Happiness is a matter of choice,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 2002, 83 (5), 1178~1197.
Schwartz, J. M. and S. Begley, The Mind and the Brain: Neuroplasticity and the Power of Mental Force. New York, NY: HarperCollins Publishers Inc., 2002. 洪蘭(譯),《重塑大腦》,台北市:時報文化,2003。
Shang, J. and R. Croson, “A field experiment in charitable contribution: The impact of social information on the voluntary provision of public goods,” The Economic Journal, 2009, 119 (540), 1422-1439.
Shavell, S., “Law versus morality as regulators of conduct,” American Law and Economics, 2002, 4, 227-257.
Simon, H. A., “Altruism and economics,” The American Economic Review, 1993, 83 (2), 156-161.
____________ Models of Bounded Rationality: Economic Analysis and Public Policy. 1, MA: MIT Press, 1984.
Simons, J. M. and R. G. Charles, “Saturation of subjective reward magnitude as a function of current and pulse frequency,” Behavioral Neuroscience, 1994, 108, 151-160.
Smith, A., The Theory of Moral Sentiments. 6th ed. London: A. Millar, 1790.
Stones, M. J., A. Kozma, J. Hirdes, D. Gold, T. Arbuckle, P. Kolopack, “Short happiness and affect research protocol,” Social Indicators Research, 1996, 37 (1), 75-91.
Sugden, R., “The supply of public goods through voluntary contributions,” The Economic Journal, 1984, 94 (376), 772-787.
Thaler, R. H., “Toward a positive theory of consumer choice”, Journal of Economic Behavior Organization, 1980, 39, 36-90.
Theurer, K. and A. Wister, “Altruistic behavior and social capital as predictors of well-being among older Canadians,” Ageing and Society, 2010, 30 (1), 157-181.
Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman, , “Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference Dependent model,” the Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1991, 106, 1039-1061.
___________ “Advance in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty”, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1992, 5, 297-323.
Vesterlund, L., “The informational value of sequential fundraising,” Journal of Public Economics, 2003, 87, 627-58.
Warr, P. G., “Pareto optimal redistribution and private charity,” Journal of Public Economics, 1982, 19, 131-138.
Wheeler, L., Interpersonal Influence. Boston: Allyn And Bacon, 1970.
論文全文使用權限
校內
校內紙本論文立即公開
同意電子論文全文授權校園內公開
校內電子論文立即公開
校外
同意授權
校外電子論文立即公開

如有問題,歡迎洽詢!
圖書館數位資訊組 (02)2621-5656 轉 2487 或 來信